Applied Category Theory Course: Resource Theories

 

My course on applied category theory is continuing! After a two-week break where the students did exercises, I’m back to lecturing about Fong and Spivak’s book Seven Sketches. Now we’re talking about “resource theories”. Resource theories help us answer questions like this:

  1. Given what I have, is it possible to get what I want?
  2. Given what I have, how much will it cost to get what I want?
  3. Given what I have, how long will it take to get what I want?
  4. Given what I have, what is the set of ways to get what I want?

Resource theories in their modern form were arguably born in these papers:

• Bob Coecke, Tobias Fritz and Robert W. Spekkens, A mathematical theory of resources.

• Tobias Fritz, Resource convertibility and ordered commutative monoids.

We are lucky to have Tobias in our course, helping the discussions along! He’s already posted some articles on resource theory here on this blog:

• Tobias Fritz, Resource convertibility (part 1), Azimuth, 7 April 2015.

• Tobias Fritz, Resource convertibility (part 2), Azimuth, 10 April 2015.

• Tobias Fritz, Resource convertibility (part 3), Azimuth, 13 April 2015.

We’re having fun bouncing between the relatively abstract world of monoidal preorders and their very concrete real-world applications to chemistry, scheduling, manufacturing and other topics. Here are the lectures so far:

Lecture 18 – Chapter 2: Resource Theories
Lecture 19 – Chapter 2: Chemistry and Scheduling
Lecture 20 – Chapter 2: Manufacturing
Lecture 21 – Chapter 2: Monoidal Preorders
Lecture 22 – Chapter 2: Symmetric Monoidal Preorders
Lecture 23 – Chapter 2: Commutative Monoidal Posets
Lecture 24 – Chapter 2: Pricing Resources
Lecture 25 – Chapter 2: Reaction Networks
Lecture 26 – Chapter 2: Monoidal Monotones
Lecture 27 – Chapter 2: Adjoints of Monoidal Monotones
Lecture 28 – Chapter 2: Ignoring Externalities

 

4 Responses to Applied Category Theory Course: Resource Theories

  1. we explore a wide variety of situations—in the world of science, engineering, and commerce

    However, neither engineers, nor software developers, nor business leaders were consulted for or contributed to the development of the book.

    Am I right?

    • John Baez says:

      David Spivak helps run a software company, and he’s gotten a large grant from NASA to help design certain aspects of the air traffic control system. Does that count?

  2. John Baez says:

    I believe it’ll be fun to think about “ignoring externalities” and adjoints of monoidal monotones – I posted two puzzles about that here:

    Lecture 28 – Chapter 2: Ignoring Externalities

    The idea is that sometimes our view of a process:

    is a simplification where we ignore features of a more complex process:

    Can we go backwards and recover the more complex view from the simpler one?

  3. I’ll have too look at the puzzles but i’ll make a comment first. Since i claim to have studied some economics , economists have 2 answers–one theoretical and one pragmatic.

    Theoretically you can’t ignore externalities—only problem is, in earlier and evolving forms of economics they sort of kept finding more externalities–things they neglected to account for (e.g. things like land, water, air, biodiversity, human capital or education, social capital (‘diversity and social in/exclusion) , etc. ).

    Pragmatically, alot of economists decide to ignore externalities because it complicates the analyses, and complications incur costs–including computing time. You may have to truncate the series or algorithm (be a Turing oracle). So you may just put all the trash in the creek and it will be taken away to the ocean, rather than buy a trash can and make a dump or recycling center.

    I rarely eat sweets anymore so its hard for me to process the example–but its the same as any such process.

    In statistical physics Jarzynski in/equality or Crooks fluctuation theorem (i view them as equivalent but that’s an opinion) point out there are no externalities. My view is they formalized what had been folklore (i.e. well known knowledge, just as indigenous americans knew about potatoes before there were frito lay potato chips–they just didn’t patent them). That view points out if you ask when entropy increases in a subsystem where did the negentropy go—the answer is out in the universe. Its still there. Thats the difference between the canonical and microcanonical ensembles in statphys. In canonical there are externalities, in microcanonical there aren’t any.

You can use Markdown or HTML in your comments. You can also use LaTeX, like this: $latex E = m c^2 $. The word 'latex' comes right after the first dollar sign, with a space after it.

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

w

Connecting to %s